2023-09-28 14:46:10 +00:00
|
|
|
abstract: 'This article seeks to analyze the political economy of military
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
conscription policy and its relationship with a country''s external
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
security environment. National security is modeled as a non-rivalrous
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
and non-excludable public good, whose production technology consists of
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
either centrally conscripted or competitively recruited military labor.
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
Conscription is construed as an implicit discretionary tax on citizens''
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
labor endowment. Based on this, I propose a simple political economy
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
model of pure public goods provision financed by two policy instruments:
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
a lump-sum income tax and a conscription tax. Constraint optimization of
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
a quasi-linear utility function gives rise to three general classes of
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
preferences: high- and low-skilled citizens will prefer an all-volunteer
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
army, albeit of different size, whereas medium-skilled citizens will
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
favor positive levels of conscription. These derived preferences allow
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
me to tease out an explicit relationship between military manpower
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
procurement policy, a country''s level of external threat, and its
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
pre-tax income inequality levels. One of my key findings is that more
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
egalitarian countries are more likely to use conscription as a military
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
manpower procurement mechanism.'
|
|
|
|
affiliation: 'Konstantinidis, N (Corresponding Author), IE Univ, Sch Global \& Pubic
|
|
|
|
Affairs, C Pedro de Valdivia 21, Madrid 28006, Spain.
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
Konstantinidis, Nikitas, IE Univ, Sch Global \& Pubic Affairs, C Pedro de Valdivia
|
|
|
|
21, Madrid 28006, Spain.'
|
|
|
|
article-number: 0951629819895595
|
|
|
|
author: Konstantinidis, Nikitas
|
|
|
|
author-email: nikitas.konstantinidis@ie.edu
|
|
|
|
author_list:
|
|
|
|
- family: Konstantinidis
|
|
|
|
given: Nikitas
|
|
|
|
da: '2023-09-28'
|
|
|
|
doi: 10.1177/0951629819895595
|
|
|
|
earlyaccessdate: JAN 2020
|
|
|
|
eissn: 1460-3667
|
|
|
|
files: []
|
|
|
|
issn: 0951-6298
|
|
|
|
journal: JOURNAL OF THEORETICAL POLITICS
|
|
|
|
keywords: 'Military conscription; national security; public goods; income
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
inequality; conscription tax'
|
|
|
|
keywords-plus: DRAFT; PARTIES; SUPPORT; MODEL; ARMY; END; WAR
|
|
|
|
language: English
|
|
|
|
month: APR
|
|
|
|
number: '2'
|
|
|
|
number-of-cited-references: '42'
|
|
|
|
orcid-numbers: Konstantinidis, Nikitas/0000-0002-3132-1216
|
|
|
|
pages: 312-347
|
|
|
|
papis_id: 82b51cee0e74e584b0a1f9771f5807c0
|
|
|
|
ref: Konstantinidis2020militaryconscription
|
|
|
|
researcherid-numbers: 'Baltutyte, Gerda/AGH-5630-2022
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
Konstantinidis, Nikitas/P-6869-2016'
|
|
|
|
times-cited: '0'
|
|
|
|
title: 'Military conscription, external security, and income inequality: The missing
|
|
|
|
link'
|
2023-10-01 08:15:07 +00:00
|
|
|
type: article
|
2023-09-28 14:46:10 +00:00
|
|
|
unique-id: WOS:000510412700001
|
|
|
|
usage-count-last-180-days: '3'
|
|
|
|
usage-count-since-2013: '8'
|
|
|
|
volume: '32'
|
|
|
|
web-of-science-categories: Political Science
|
|
|
|
year: '2020'
|