wow-inequalities/02-data/intermediate/wos_sample/9b992cf19f3c73f67ce73b71660eefc6-drezner-dw/info.yaml

178 lines
5.9 KiB
YAML

abstract: 'WHEN a presidential election year coincides with an uncertain economy,
campaigning politicians invariably invoke an international economic
issue as a dire threat to the well-being of Americans. Speechwriters
denounce the chosen scapegoat, the media provides blanket coverage of
the alleged threat, and legislators scurry to introduce supposed
remedies. The cause of this year''s commotion is offshore outsourcing-the
alleged migration of American jobs overseas. The depth of alarm was
strikingly illustrated by the firestorm of reaction to recent testimony
by N. Gregory Mankiw, the head of President George W Bush''s Council of
Economic Advisers. No economist really disputed Mankiw''s observation
that ``outsourcing is just a new way of doing international trade,{''''}
which makes it ``a good thing.{''''} But in the political arena, Mankiw''s
comments sparked a furor on both sides of the aisle. Democratic
presidential candidate John Kerry accused the Bush administration of
wanting ``to export more of our jobs overseas,{''''} and Senate Minority
Leader Tom Daschle quipped, ``If this is the administratior''s position,
I think they owe an apology to every worker in America.{''''} Speaker of
the House Dennis Hastert, meanwhile, warned that ``outsourcing can be a
problem for American workers and the American economy.{''''}
Critics charge that the information revolution (especially the Internet)
has accelerated the decimation of U.S. manufacturing and facilitated the
outsourcing of service-sector jobs once considered safe, from backroom
call centers to high-level software programming. (This concern feeds
into the suspicion that U.S. corporations are exploiting globalization
to fatten profits at the expense of workers.) They are right that
offshore outsourcing deserves attention and that some measures to assist
affected workers are called for. But if their exaggerated alarmism
succeeds in provoking protectionist responses from lawmakers, it will do
far more harm than good, to the U.S. economy and to American workers. S
hould Americans be concerned about the economic effects of outsourcing?
Not particularly. Most of the numbers thrown around are vague, overhyped
estimates. What hard data exist suggest that gross job losses due to
offshore outsourcing have been minimal when compared to the size of the
entire U.S. economy. The outsourcing phenomenon has shown that
globalization can affect white-collar professions, heretofore immune to
foreign competition, in the same way that it has affected manufacturing
jobs for years. But Mankiw''s statements on outsourcing are absolutely
correct; the law of comparative advantage does not stop working just
because 401(K)plans are involved. The creation of new jobs overseas will
eventually lead to more jobs and higher incomes in the United States.
Because the economy and especially job growth-is sluggish at the moment,
commentators are attempting to draw a connection between offshore
outsourcing and high unemployment. But believing that offshore
outsourcing causes unemployment is the economic equivalent of believing
that the sun revolves around the earth: intuitively compelling but
clearly wrong.
Should Americans be concerned about the political backlash to
outsourcing? Absolutely. Anecdotes of workers affected by outsourcing
are politically powerful, and demands for government protection always
increase during economic slowdowns. The short-term political appeal of
protectionism is undeniable. Scapegoating foreigners for domestic
business cycles is smart politics, and protecting domestic markets gives
leaders the appearance of taking direct, decisive action on the economy.
Protectionism would not solve the U.S. economy''s employment problems,
although it would succeed in providing massive subsidies to
well-organized interest groups. In open markets, greater competition
spurs the reallocation of labor and capital to more profitable sectors
of the economy. The benefits of such free trade-to both consumers and
producers-are significant. Cushioning this process for displaced
however, sales-making TAA out of reach for those affected by it. It
makes sense to rework TAA rules to take into account workers displaced
by offshore outsourcing even when their former industries or firms
maintain robust levels of production.
Another option would be to help firms purchase targeted insurance
policies to offset the transition costs to workers directly affected by
offshore outsourcing. Because the perception of possible unemployment is
considerably greater than the actual likelihood of losing a job,
insurance programs would impose a very small cost on firms while
relieving a great deal of employee anxiety. McKinsey Global Institute
estimates that such a scheme could be created for as little as four or
five cents per dollar saved from offshore outsourcing. IBM recently
announced the creation of a two-year, \$25 million retraining fund for
its employees who fear job losses from outsourcing. Having the private
sector handle the problem without extensive government intervention
would be an added bonus.'
affiliation: 'Drezner, DW (Corresponding Author), Univ Chicago, Chicago, IL 60637
USA.
Univ Chicago, Chicago, IL 60637 USA.'
author: Drezner, DW
author_list:
- family: Drezner
given: DW
da: '2023-09-28'
doi: 10.2307/20033973
files: []
issn: 0015-7120
journal: FOREIGN AFFAIRS
language: English
month: MAY-JUN
number: '3'
number-of-cited-references: '0'
pages: 22+
papis_id: 9d2ad769ef14983f73aee051ea264827
ref: Drezner2004outsourcingbogeyman
times-cited: '43'
title: The outsourcing bogeyman
type: article
unique-id: WOS:000220771200004
usage-count-last-180-days: '0'
usage-count-since-2013: '33'
volume: '83'
web-of-science-categories: International Relations
year: '2004'