abstract: 'In this paper practical and political problems concerning the transformation of the social security system in agriculture of the `old'' Federal Republic of Germany to the New Federal States are discussed. The intention is to analyse the impacts of transferring this system to East Germany, especially concerning social security matters and their financial and distributive effects. Furthermore some conclusions from the East German experiences for the transformation of the social policy systems for the agricultural sectors in Central and Eastern European countries (CEECs) are drawn. Since insight into the interdependencies of polity politics and policies are important for a successful guidance the political determinants of policy-making in this sector in unified Germany are examined too. In comparison with the CEECs the transformation process in East Germany has to Se dealt with as a special case. The very rapid transition from a planned economy to a market economy lead to a drastic reduction of jobs particularly in the agricultural sector of East Germany. But unlike other CEECs in transition, a whole string of government programmes has been adopted and contributed a lot to make this process socially acceptable. The transfers from the federal budget to the New Lander amounted to 615 billion DM from 1991 to 1995; approximately 40 per cent (215 billion DM) has been spent on social policy measures, mainly for the labour market policy measures. In this respect, the New Federal States found themselves in a unique situation which gave them a rather privileged position, facilitating and mitigating the required changes. A further consequence of this general framework of transition was that the transformation in the New Federal States meant in almost every economic sector the transfer of the West German institutions. The structure of agricultural enterprises in East Germany differed, however, considerably from the West German family farms. Therefore, a sob adoption of West German institutions of social security policy for the agricultural sector in the New Federal States was problematic: On the one hand it seemed questionable whether this scheme was applicable to the special situation and particular social security demands of the farm population in the New Federal States. On the other band the agricultural social security system in the Federal Republic of Germany had become an important instrument of agricultural income policy at the national level. Since it is highly subsidised the question arised how this would influence the competitiveness between different legal forms of farm enterprises. Hence political decision makers were in a dilemma: introducing the special agricultural insurance system without any significant changes in the financing system would exclude many registered cooperatives from subsidies of considerable amount. So an alternative policy-option was to reform the system by decoupling the social security policy for agriculture from income: policy objectives and reforming it using the social insurance systems for employees as a point of reference. Politicians have chosen different options in transferring the social security system in agriculture of the Old Federal States to the New Federal States. In health and accident insurance the policy-option of an unchanged transfer of the West German institutions was preferred. In the old age pension scheme the policy-option of a transfer was linked with a partial reform of the system, reducing the distributive advantages of the sectoral system. With the exception of the agricultural accident insurance covering an types of farm enterprises the working population in agriculture is treated in accordance to their status as self employed or employees. Whereas agricultural entrepreneurs are included into the sectoral systems, agricultural employees remain in the general statutory systems. This was a reasonable solution in terms of the different social needs of both groups. Comparing the distributive effects of the two systems however shows, that there are still considerable advantages for the farmers'' system, despite a remarkable reform of the farmer''s old age pension scheme. Explaining these policy outcomes in social security policy in agriculture has to focus on changing policy networks before and after German unification. The path-dependency and in some way contingency of the policy process and its results make it almost impossible to draw general conclusions, in order to provide guidance as to how to manage reform processes in agricultural policy. Due to the fact that all CEECs are undertaking or initiating reforms of their social security systems, however, these countries do have a particular interest to find the best possible solutions for the social problems they are involved, bearing in mind, however, that a social security system cannot simply be copied from another country. A look at social security systems in West European countries demonstrates the wide range of possibilities available for organizing social security. In Central and East European countries too there was not one single socialist system of social security policy. Hence, CEECs have to reform their own schemes due to the overall conditions and the historical backgrounds in each country. This does not, however, imply that experiences from social security in western democratic countries or the transformation process in East Germany may not be of interest to the other states undergoing transformation. In all 15 member countries of the EU employees in agriculture and self-employed farmers as well are covered by comprehensive compulsory insurance schemes. But especially the insurance schemes for farmers, obligatorily insured in old age pension schemes in all states, are very heterogenously organized. Partly, farmers are insured in special agricultural systems or in social security systems for self-employed persons, partly, farmers are members of the general social security systems. Despite great varieties in entitlement rules, insured persons, level of benefits etc. all sectoral systems for farmers have the following in common: more old age pensioners than contributors; a high dependency on state subsidies; a low level of pensions and problems of compatibility with other old age pension schemes, if a farmer decides to change occupation. Up to now among the CEECs only Poland has a special system of old age pensions for farmers. In the other CEECs, farmers as well as the entire working population in agriculture were insured within the general system. Experiences in Poland with KRUS, the agricultural social security fund, are similiar to those in Western European countries with special security systems for farmers. Looking at the experiences in the FRG, in the other West-European countries with special systems for farmers and in Poland, it seems not to be a recommendable solution for other CEECs to follow these examples.' affiliation: Mehl, P (Corresponding Author), BUNDESFORSCH ANSTALT LANDWIRTSCHAFT BRAUNSCHWEIG,INST STRUKTURFORSCH,BRAUNSCHWEIG,GERMANY. author: Mehl, P author_list: - family: Mehl given: P da: '2023-09-28' files: [] issn: 0458-6859 journal: LANDBAUFORSCHUNG VOLKENRODE language: English number: '2' number-of-cited-references: '59' pages: 75-88 papis_id: c54e138da5d195dfebea43144044cf31 ref: Mehl1997transformingsocial times-cited: '0' title: 'Transforming social security in agriculture in transition countries: The case of East Germany' type: article unique-id: WOS:A1997YA11300004 usage-count-last-180-days: '0' usage-count-since-2013: '13' volume: '47' web-of-science-categories: Agriculture, Multidisciplinary year: '1997'