abstract: 'WHEN a presidential election year coincides with an uncertain economy, campaigning politicians invariably invoke an international economic issue as a dire threat to the well-being of Americans. Speechwriters denounce the chosen scapegoat, the media provides blanket coverage of the alleged threat, and legislators scurry to introduce supposed remedies. The cause of this year''s commotion is offshore outsourcing-the alleged migration of American jobs overseas. The depth of alarm was strikingly illustrated by the firestorm of reaction to recent testimony by N. Gregory Mankiw, the head of President George W Bush''s Council of Economic Advisers. No economist really disputed Mankiw''s observation that ``outsourcing is just a new way of doing international trade,{''''} which makes it ``a good thing.{''''} But in the political arena, Mankiw''s comments sparked a furor on both sides of the aisle. Democratic presidential candidate John Kerry accused the Bush administration of wanting ``to export more of our jobs overseas,{''''} and Senate Minority Leader Tom Daschle quipped, ``If this is the administratior''s position, I think they owe an apology to every worker in America.{''''} Speaker of the House Dennis Hastert, meanwhile, warned that ``outsourcing can be a problem for American workers and the American economy.{''''} Critics charge that the information revolution (especially the Internet) has accelerated the decimation of U.S. manufacturing and facilitated the outsourcing of service-sector jobs once considered safe, from backroom call centers to high-level software programming. (This concern feeds into the suspicion that U.S. corporations are exploiting globalization to fatten profits at the expense of workers.) They are right that offshore outsourcing deserves attention and that some measures to assist affected workers are called for. But if their exaggerated alarmism succeeds in provoking protectionist responses from lawmakers, it will do far more harm than good, to the U.S. economy and to American workers. S hould Americans be concerned about the economic effects of outsourcing? Not particularly. Most of the numbers thrown around are vague, overhyped estimates. What hard data exist suggest that gross job losses due to offshore outsourcing have been minimal when compared to the size of the entire U.S. economy. The outsourcing phenomenon has shown that globalization can affect white-collar professions, heretofore immune to foreign competition, in the same way that it has affected manufacturing jobs for years. But Mankiw''s statements on outsourcing are absolutely correct; the law of comparative advantage does not stop working just because 401(K)plans are involved. The creation of new jobs overseas will eventually lead to more jobs and higher incomes in the United States. Because the economy and especially job growth-is sluggish at the moment, commentators are attempting to draw a connection between offshore outsourcing and high unemployment. But believing that offshore outsourcing causes unemployment is the economic equivalent of believing that the sun revolves around the earth: intuitively compelling but clearly wrong. Should Americans be concerned about the political backlash to outsourcing? Absolutely. Anecdotes of workers affected by outsourcing are politically powerful, and demands for government protection always increase during economic slowdowns. The short-term political appeal of protectionism is undeniable. Scapegoating foreigners for domestic business cycles is smart politics, and protecting domestic markets gives leaders the appearance of taking direct, decisive action on the economy. Protectionism would not solve the U.S. economy''s employment problems, although it would succeed in providing massive subsidies to well-organized interest groups. In open markets, greater competition spurs the reallocation of labor and capital to more profitable sectors of the economy. The benefits of such free trade-to both consumers and producers-are significant. Cushioning this process for displaced however, sales-making TAA out of reach for those affected by it. It makes sense to rework TAA rules to take into account workers displaced by offshore outsourcing even when their former industries or firms maintain robust levels of production. Another option would be to help firms purchase targeted insurance policies to offset the transition costs to workers directly affected by offshore outsourcing. Because the perception of possible unemployment is considerably greater than the actual likelihood of losing a job, insurance programs would impose a very small cost on firms while relieving a great deal of employee anxiety. McKinsey Global Institute estimates that such a scheme could be created for as little as four or five cents per dollar saved from offshore outsourcing. IBM recently announced the creation of a two-year, \$25 million retraining fund for its employees who fear job losses from outsourcing. Having the private sector handle the problem without extensive government intervention would be an added bonus.' affiliation: 'Drezner, DW (Corresponding Author), Univ Chicago, Chicago, IL 60637 USA. Univ Chicago, Chicago, IL 60637 USA.' author: Drezner, DW author_list: - family: Drezner given: DW da: '2023-09-28' doi: 10.2307/20033973 files: [] issn: 0015-7120 journal: FOREIGN AFFAIRS language: English month: MAY-JUN number: '3' number-of-cited-references: '0' pages: 22+ papis_id: 9d2ad769ef14983f73aee051ea264827 ref: Drezner2004outsourcingbogeyman times-cited: '43' title: The outsourcing bogeyman type: Article unique-id: WOS:000220771200004 usage-count-last-180-days: '0' usage-count-since-2013: '33' volume: '83' web-of-science-categories: International Relations year: '2004'